Skip to main content

Krugman & Gould, I

File:Stephen Jay Gould by Kathy Chapman.png

Headnote: I have just learned that the great scholar Jacques Barzun has died. It is hardly a life cut short -- he was born on November 30, 1907, so he was about a month short of turning 105. Still, for those of us to whom his life and work mattered, he had come to seem immortal. And in any sense that scholarship can secure: he is. For now, I will proceed with the material prepared for this and the following two entries in this blog. But I will have more to say about Barzun here soon enough.]


Stephen Jay Gould, the paleontologist who did a good deal to educate the non-scientists of the world about the biology of evolution, passed away back in 2002. He might be surprised to learn that his name has now become a bone of contention [a fossilized bone of contention?] among economists.

Of course it isn't all that surprising that there should be cross-fertilization between biology and economics. Ask Malthus about this. Ask Herbert Spencer. Still, my understanding is that this wasn't a list Gould wanted to join.

Economist Paul Krugman seems to see himself in terms analogous to those in which Gould saw himself: a guy who knows all the technical stuff yet who can write for the common folk without the specialized education, too. So much the stranger, then, that it was Krugman who years ago took some rather idle unnecessary shots at Gould, shots that have still more oddly only just now set off a kerfuffle.

In 1998, in an essay on why "intellectuals" don't seem to grasp certain economic theories, Krugman named Gould as someone who makes "a great show of offering new ideas" while leaving it "quite hard to pin down just what those new ideas really are." Krugman clearly preferred Dawkins over Gould as an explicator of biology. Gould "doesn't even think in terms of the mathematical models that inform the work of writers like Dawkins."

What Krugman was trying to say was this: science works and advances through mathematical models. People who don't 'get it' like to be re-assured that the mathematical models aren't really important. People with apparently good credentials who offer them that re-assurance are widening the gap between populace and experts. Shame on them.

The specific economic theory that Krugman was defending here was the Ricardian theory of "comparative advantage." The theory (without math) is this:

1) if England is better at making textiles than it is at growing grapes, and Portugal is better at growing grapes than it is at manufacturing textiles, then both countries and their populations will be better off if England sticks to making clothes and Portugal sticks to grape juice and wine. That way, England can send Portugal clothes, and Portugal can send England beverages

2) not only does international trade obviously result from specialization in such a context, but international trade also induces specialization: when and to the extent that there is open free trade between the two countries, the tendency will be for English vinyards and Portuguese textile mills both to go out of business, for laborers and other resources to move toward the comparative advantage in  each case, and finally

3) that is itself a powerful argument for keeping trade free.

Krugman accepts that theory of free trade as essentially true, and his own Nobel Prize winning work has come from advancing understanding of the mathematical details that go with it.

But of late, Nassim Nicholas Taleb has taken shots at Krugman, and in attempted vindication of Gould.

Who is Taleb? He is a Lebanese-American writer on finance. One of his many academic affiliations is Distinguished Research Scholar, Said Business School, Oxford University.  He has written two books for popular audiences, Fooled by Randomness, and The Black Swan.  Next month he has a new book coming out, under the title Antifragile.

So what does he have against Krugman and/or Ricardo? or is he just defensive on behalf of Gould?

I'll continue this exposition tomorrow.





Comments

Popular posts from this blog

A Story About Coleridge

This is a quote from a memoir by Dorothy Wordsworth, reflecting on a trip she took with two famous poets, her brother, William Wordsworth, and their similarly gifted companion, Samuel Taylor Coleridge.   We sat upon a bench, placed for the sake of one of these views, whence we looked down upon the waterfall, and over the open country ... A lady and gentleman, more expeditious tourists than ourselves, came to the spot; they left us at the seat, and we found them again at another station above the Falls. Coleridge, who is always good-natured enough to enter into conversation with anybody whom he meets in his way, began to talk with the gentleman, who observed that it was a majestic waterfall. Coleridge was delighted with the accuracy of the epithet, particularly as he had been settling in his own mind the precise meaning of the words grand, majestic, sublime, etc., and had discussed the subject with William at some length the day before. “Yes, sir,” says Coleridge, “it is a majesti

Five Lessons from the Allegory of the Cave

  Please correct me if there are others. But it seems to be there are five lessons the reader is meant to draw from the story about the cave.   First, Plato  is working to devalue what we would call empiricism. He is saying that keeping track of the shadows on the cave wall, trying to make sense of what you see there, will NOT get you to wisdom. Second, Plato is contending that reality comes in levels. The shadows on the wall are illusions. The solid objects being passed around behind my back are more real than their shadows are. BUT … the world outside the the cave is more real than that — and the sun by which that world is illuminated is the top of the hierarchy. So there isn’t a binary choice of real/unreal. There are levels. Third, he equates realness with knowability.  I  only have opinions about the shadows. Could I turn around, I could have at least the glimmerings of knowledge. Could I get outside the cave, I would really Know. Fourth, the parable assigns a task to philosophers

Searle: The Chinese Room

John Searle has become the object of accusations of improper conduct. These accusations even have some people in the world of academic philosophy saying that instructors in that world should try to avoid teaching Searle's views. That is an odd contention, and has given rise to heated exchanges in certain corners of the blogosphere.  At Leiter Reports, I encountered a comment from someone describing himself as "grad student drop out." GSDO said: " This is a side question (and not at all an attempt to answer the question BL posed): How important is John Searle's work? Are people still working on speech act theory or is that just another dead end in the history of 20th century philosophy? My impression is that his reputation is somewhat inflated from all of his speaking engagements and NYRoB reviews. The Chinese room argument is a classic, but is there much more to his work than that?" I took it upon myself to answer that on LR. But here I'll tak