Skip to main content

Risk-return tradeoff and the U.S. treasury

In our last post devoted to the mathematics of finance, we mentioned that the standard deviation of a bell curve showing the range of possible returns from an asset can be employed as a surrogate for its risk. I'd like to pursue that point a bit.

It is the chanciest corporations, the ones that do have significant risk, that have to bribe you into buying their bonds with a higher return than their safer brethren need offer: thus, a trade-off.

One way of looking at the trade-off is this: suppose I come into your neighborhood and offer to play a simple game. You will roll a pair of dice I provide and I will give you $1,000 times the number shown on the dice when they come to rest. I require only that you pay me $1,000 before we begin.
The lowest possible score is 2, so the lowest possible pay-out is twice what you’ll pay me up front. This, then, (if I am honest and actually have the money I’m offering to pay) is a can’t-lose proposition for you. The worst outcome is you gain $1,000. The best outcome is that you gain $11,000 [(12x1,000) - $1,000.] In this case, the variance among the outcomes doesn’t amount to risk in the intuitive sense of the word at all.

But in finance (as in life generally) such no-lose propositions are rare and fleeting. Suppose I start offering to let you and your neighbors bid on who will play the game next. Wouldn’t you, or someone else in the group, be likely to bid something higher than $1,000?  Something higher, even, than $2,000? If the winner bidder agrees to pay $2,001, then he has agreed to risk $1. It is possible, after all, that he will roll snake eyes, and collect only $2,000 back from me after paying that $2,001.

Eventually, I will be playing only with those in the neighborhood who are most tolerant of risk, and my operation, which began as so blatant a money-losing extravagance, may even start turning me a profit. The possibility of that big $12,000 return is what is drawing people to my auctions, rendering them willing to take some risk: and in such cases the variance of results is, as Markowitz noted, a convenient way to quantify that risk.

In order to give some formal elegance to the idea of a risk-return trade-off, economists often talk about the risk-free rate of return, which is called r.  Until quite recently, and throughout the period when economists were busily formulating the key notions of modern finance theory, the return on U.S. Treasury bills served as an empirically-observable proof of r. In a formula that contains that letter, simply plug in that return as r and carry on.
 
In 2011, though, the world changed. After a months-long political deadlock brought the U.S. close to default, and produced a debt-ceiling deal promising further work on fiscal issues in a way that seemed to many observers just … not credible, one of the big three credit rating companies downgraded U.S. Treasuries, from AAA to AA+.

Through simple inertia, T-bills are still often used for r, but when this is done explicitly, it is done almost apologetically. Howard Marks, co-founder of Oaktree Capital, told me soon thereafter (“speaking as a non-quant”) that there may be no riskless place in the world, but that short T-bills are still “essentially” riskless.
 
Irene Aldridge, managing partner at ABLE Alpha Trading, has said that she would lean toward the use of a basket of the bonds of the most secure U.S. municipalities as the better risk-free benchmark.  

But let’s get back to the question with which we began: what moves stock prices. The trade-off we’ve discussed worked among asset classes and within any asset class. Thus, on the one hand,  the world of stocks is (in accord with the ideas we’ve outlined thus far) both higher risk and higher return than the world of sovereign or corporate bonds. Within stocks as an asset class, there is again a wide variation as to both risk and return. 

If ECMH is valid, then one would expect that the price of a stock will reflect its risk, both its historical volatility and all publicly available information that bears on that risk. We should accordingly redefine alpha. We defined it above at a first approximation as the excess (or deficit) of an actively managed performance beyond what an investor could get from a passively managed investment. We should add here that alpha as a technical term also includes a risk premium. So it is the risk adjusted excess (or deficit) return that an investor can get in reference to a passive benchmark.  

ECMH is only valid (indeed, it is only even plausible) for highly liquid, high-volume markets. We can see this if we state the argument in its favor carefully.  

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

A Story About Coleridge

This is a quote from a memoir by Dorothy Wordsworth, reflecting on a trip she took with two famous poets, her brother, William Wordsworth, and their similarly gifted companion, Samuel Taylor Coleridge.   We sat upon a bench, placed for the sake of one of these views, whence we looked down upon the waterfall, and over the open country ... A lady and gentleman, more expeditious tourists than ourselves, came to the spot; they left us at the seat, and we found them again at another station above the Falls. Coleridge, who is always good-natured enough to enter into conversation with anybody whom he meets in his way, began to talk with the gentleman, who observed that it was a majestic waterfall. Coleridge was delighted with the accuracy of the epithet, particularly as he had been settling in his own mind the precise meaning of the words grand, majestic, sublime, etc., and had discussed the subject with William at some length the day before. “Yes, sir,” says Coleridge, “it is a maj...

Searle: The Chinese Room

John Searle has become the object of accusations of improper conduct. These accusations even have some people in the world of academic philosophy saying that instructors in that world should try to avoid teaching Searle's views. That is an odd contention, and has given rise to heated exchanges in certain corners of the blogosphere.  At Leiter Reports, I encountered a comment from someone describing himself as "grad student drop out." GSDO said: " This is a side question (and not at all an attempt to answer the question BL posed): How important is John Searle's work? Are people still working on speech act theory or is that just another dead end in the history of 20th century philosophy? My impression is that his reputation is somewhat inflated from all of his speaking engagements and NYRoB reviews. The Chinese room argument is a classic, but is there much more to his work than that?" I took it upon myself to answer that on LR. But here I'll tak...

Recent Controversies Involving Nassim Taleb, Part I

I've written about Nassim Taleb on earlier occasions in this blog. I'll let you do the search yourself, dear reader, for the full background. The short answer to the question "who is Taleb?" is this: he is a 57 year old man born in Lebanon, educated in France, who has been both a hedge fund manager and a derivatives trader. He retired from active participation from the financial world sometime between 2004 and 2006, and has been a full-time writer and provocateur ever since. Taleb's writings for the general public began where one might expect -- in the field where he had made his money -- and he explained certain financial issues to a broad audiences in a very dramatic non-technical way. Since then, he has widened has fields of study, writing about just about everything, applying the intellectual tools he honed in that earlier work. As you might have gather from the above, I respect Taleb, though I have sometimes been critical of him when my own writing ab...